The Luxembourg Competition Authority dismisses an RPM allegation against a dairy products manufacturer due to the lack of evidence that a vertical agreement exists
The Luxembourg Competition
Authority dismisses an RPM allegation against a dairy products manufacturer due
to the lack of evidence that a vertical agreement exists
In the Luxlait case
(decision of 26 June 2018 no. 2018-FO-03, Luxlait Association Agricole,
Luxlait-Expansion S.A., Nouvelle Luxlait Produits Sarl, Luxlait Distribution SA
(Luxlait), www.concurrence.lu) the Luxembourg Competition
Authority (LCA) opened an antitrust investigation against a manufacturer of a
dairy products that was alleged to have determined the minimum prices for retailers
to apply to its dairy products. Eventually, the LCA closed the investigation
with a non-infringement decision because no vertical restraint could be found to
the requisite evidentiary standard.
The facts of the caase
Luxlait Association Agricole together with its
subsidiaries (hereinafter referred as Luxlait) were active in the production
and distribution of milk and dairy products. In 2010 an undisclosed
hard-discount retailer (the complainant) lodged a report with the LCA alleging
that Luxlait put in place anti-competitive pricing vertical restraints. The
complaining hard-discount retailer reported that Luxlait refused to deal with
it because of its denial to adhere to the minimum resale prices recommended by Luxlait
to its distributors and retailers. While the complainant pursued an aggressive
pricing policy being committed to apply to customers the lowest prices on the
market, the intent of Luxlait was to strictly control the resale prices and rebates
applied by its distributors. To deal with the Luxlait refusal, in April 2009
the complainant concluded a contract with a distributor, Cogel SA (Cogel), for
the supply of a number of Luxlait products. But some months later Cogel
terminated the supply contract because, in the view of the complainant, it yielded
to pressure from Luxlait.
The decision of the LCA
Following the receipt of the complainant’s report, the
LCA decided to open an antitrust investigation against Luxlait on the ground of
Article 3 of the Law of 23 October 2011 (Luxembourg Competition Law or LCL), corresponding
to Article 101 TFEU, and of Article 101 TFEU itself. The relevant market affected
by the practices under scrutiny was determined by the LCA as the retail market for
four categories of dairy products marketed by Luxlait in Luxembourg.
The theory of competition harm taken by the LCA was that
Luxlait adopted a resale price maintenance practice (RPM). If an agreement
between a manufacturer and dealers is established, the contractual provisions fixing
RPM constitute a competition restraint by object. For an agreement between
manufacturers and suppliers to be inferred, a concurrence of wills between the
parties must be found, which it may be difficult where there is no direct
documentary evidence of the agreement.
To establish a RPM the LCA applied the methodology followed
by the French Competition Authority and French judges, which have crafted a
three-limb test (Court of Appeal of Paris, judgment of 28 January 2009, Epsé Joué Club; Court of Appeal of
Paris, judgment of 26 January 2012, Beauté
Prestige International). Under this
test, where it is not possible to reach a direct proof of the vertical
agreement, RPM can be established on the basis of precise, serious and
concurring indicia on the following elements:
1)Resale prices have been discussed by suppliers and
distributors;
2)A pricing policy or, alternatively, price monitoring
mechanisms have been put in place;
3)Distributors have effectively applied the recommended
resale prices.
To sum it up, for a restrictive vertical price-fixing agreement
to be found, all the above indicated conditions have to be cumulatively
fulfilled. That said, the LCA went on apply the test.
First condition – consideration
of resale prices
This condition is generally met when the recommended
resale prices are communicated by manufacturers to distributors. The evidentiary
documents considered collected by the LCA clearly showed that Luxlait
communicated to its dealers and retailers the minimum resale prices. This circumstance
was confirmed by the statements made by Luxlait and several retailers.
Third condition-
effective application of recommended resale prices
The LCA took the position that this condition was met
as shown by survey conducted by Nielsen, documents collected at the premises of
Luxlait and the responses made by retailers to the LCA information requests. These
elements indicated that retailers have effectively applied the prices
recommended by Luxlait.
Second condition-
existence of pricing policy/price monitoring
Regular pricing monitoring may not suffice to meet
this condition which is instead satisfied where manufacturers threaten to retaliate
against distributors who failed to adhere to the recommended prices. Several circumstances
have been submitted by the complainant in that regard but none of them could be
taken as satisfactory evidence of the existence of the Luxlait pricing policy.
First, in July 2008, a distributor, la Provençale,
terminated a supply contract it had entered with the complainant in December
2007 for the supply of Eskimo trademarked ice-creams produced by Luxlait. Being
uncertain whether the termination contract was an autonomous decision of la
Provençale or provoked by the interference of Luxlait, the LCA stated that there
was no causality link between the refusal of supply of la Provençale and the
Luxlait pricing policy. Therefore, the conduct of with la Provençale could not
be attributed to Luxlait.
Second, the fact that Luxlait had repetitively refused
to deal with the complainants was not a valid evidence of the manufacturer’s pricing
policy. On the contrary, other facts in the file of the case suggested that the
refusal of deal could be explained by reasons other than the complainant
refusal to apply the recommended prices.
Third, on 15 May 2009, a representative from Luxlait turned
up at the premises of the complainant to buy all the Luxlait products furnished
by third parties. Though Luxlait did not explain this act, the LCA believed
that, in light of the tense relationship between Luxlait and the complainant,
there could a plausible explanation for this event other than the pricing
policy of the manufacturer.
Fourth, another hard-discount retailer based in Luxembourg,
Lidl, experienced difficulties in dealing with Luxlait. Evidence did not indicate
that the reasons why Lidl and Luxlait failed to enter into a supply contract
was because they disagreed on resale prices. It should be also stressed that,
later, in February 2018, Lidl eventually signed a supply contract with Luxlait.
Fifth, the LCA believed that the several documents
collected at the Luxlait premises (internal mails and mails sent to its
distributors) concerning the relations between the manufacturer and dealers
cast doubts on whether the Luxlait pricing policy complied with competition. Notwithstanding
its competition concerns, the available pieces of evidence did not allow to establish
to the requisite standard the existence of the Luxlait pricing policy.
Sixth, the LCA looked at the pricing monitoring put in
place by Luxlait. In that regard, it considered the charts drafted by Luxlait
and several internal mails concerning resale prices. Again, these documents did
not prove the existence of Luxlait pricing monitoring. Whether a manufacturer
shows interest in the resale prices applied by retailers does not necessary
mean that it breaches competition. Furthermore, even if Luxlait was observing
the retail prices nothing in the case indicated that it retaliated against the
retailers that did not adhere to the recommended prices.
In conclusion, the conducts of Luxlait did not satisfy
the second condition of the test and, accordingly no vertical restraint in the
shape of RPM could be established. The LCA stressed that Luxlait was merely monitoring
the retail prices and it was not possible to infer that its conducts went
beyond it. Moreover, the elements adduced by Luxlait suggested a plausible
alternative explanation other than the existence of a pricing policy. Finally, the
indicia that supported the existence of a pricing policy were neutralized by
other facts. On balance, there was no clear proof that the market conduct of
Luxlait unequivocally amounted to a restrictive vertical restraint in the shape
of RPM. As a consequence, the LCA closed the proceedings with a no-infringement
decision, acquitting Luxlait of any allegations of breaching competition.
Conclusion
In Luxlait a
hard-discount retailer, disgruntled by the refusal of a supplier to deal with,
counterattacked using competition law as a sword to claim that such refusal to
deal was part of a wider anticompetitive RPM practice pursued by the supplier. For
suppliers giving dealers and retailers price guidelines can be a key aspect of
their marketing strategy. It is then important to clearly determine when such
practice is a unilateral conduct, which does not attract the attention of
competition authorities unless it constitutes an abuse of dominant position, or
it is an unlawful vertical restraint.
Consistently with its past decisional practice (Case
no. 2016-AS-05, SCAB), the LCA
determined this case by applying the three-limb crafted by French authorities. In
this way, the LCA confirmed the standard of proof required for the purpose of
establishing RPM and also gave guidance on the relevant facts and circumstances
to meet the second condition of the test, the existence of a pricing policy. In
essence, simply observing the resale prices charged by retailers did not suffice,
further factors being required to find a pricing policy. Because the further
factors considered in Luxlait could be interpreted in different ways, they were
too equivocal to infer that the supplier had effectively put in place a pricing
policy.
Comments